Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • The following content is provided under a Creative

  • Commons license.

  • Your support will help MIT OpenCourseWare

  • continue to offer high quality educational resources for free.

  • To make a donation, or to view additional materials

  • from hundreds of MIT courses, visit MIT OpenCourseWare

  • at ocw.mit.edu.

  • ANDREW LO: Well, let me pick up where we left off last time

  • and give you just a very quick overview of where we're at now,

  • because we're on the brink of a very important set of results

  • that I think will change your perspective permanently

  • on risk and expected return.

  • Last time, remember, we looked at this trade-off

  • between expected return and volatility.

  • And we made the argument that when

  • you combined a bunch of different securities

  • that are not all perfectly correlated,

  • what you get is this bullet-shaped curve in terms

  • of the possible trade-offs between that expected return

  • and riskiness of various different portfolios.

  • So every single dot on this bullet-shaped curve

  • corresponds to a specific portfolio, or weighting,

  • or vector of portfolio weights, omega.

  • So now what I want to ask you to do for the next lecture or two

  • is to exhibit a little bit of a split personality

  • kind of a perspective.

  • I'm going to ask you to look at the geometry of risk

  • and expected return, but at the same time,

  • in the back of your brain, I want

  • you to keep in mind the analytics

  • of that set of geometries.

  • In other words, I want you to keep in mind how we

  • got this bullet-shaped curve.

  • The way we got it was from taking

  • different weighted averages of the securities

  • that we have access to as investments.

  • So every one of these points on the bullet

  • corresponds to a specific weighting.

  • As you change those weightings, you

  • change the risk and return characteristics

  • of your portfolio.

  • So the example that I gave after showing you this

  • curve where I argued that the upper branch of this bullet

  • is where any rational person would want to be.

  • And by rational, I've defined that as somebody

  • who prefers more expected return to less, and somebody

  • who prefers less risk to more, other things equal.

  • So if you've got those kind of preferences,

  • then you want to be in the Northeast.

  • You want to be as north, sorry, Northwest as possible.

  • And you would never want to be down in this lower branch when

  • you could be in the upper branch because you'd

  • have a higher expected return for the same level of risk.

  • So after we developed this basic idea,

  • I gave you this numerical example

  • where you've got three stocks in your universe.

  • General Motors, IBM, and Motorola.

  • And these are the parameters that we've estimated

  • using historical data.

  • Now there's going to be a question,

  • and we've already raised that question, of how stable

  • are these parameters.

  • Are they really parameters, or do they change over time.

  • And I told you, in reality of course, they change over time.

  • But for now, let's play the game and assume

  • that they are constant over time,

  • and see what we can do with those parameters.

  • So with the means, the standard deviations,

  • and most importantly, the covariance matrix--

  • So this is the matrix of variances and covariances--

  • With these data as inputs, we can now

  • construct that bullet-shaped curve.

  • The way we do it is of course, to recognize

  • that the expected return of the portfolio

  • is just a weighted average of the expected returns

  • of the component securities, where the weights are

  • our choice variables.

  • That's what we are getting to pick,

  • is how we allocate the 100% of our wealth

  • to these three different securities.

  • And the variance, of course, is going

  • to be given by a somewhat more complicated expression where

  • you have the individual security variances entering here

  • from the diagonals.

  • But you also have the off diagonal terms

  • entering in that same equation for that variance

  • of the portfolio.

  • And when we put these two equations together,

  • the mean and the variance, and we take the square root

  • the variance to get the standard deviation,

  • and we plot it on a graph, we get this.

  • This is the curve, the bullet-shaped curve,

  • that we generate just from three securities,

  • and from their covariances.

  • And where we left off last time is

  • that I pointed out a couple of things that was

  • interesting about this curve.

  • One is that unlike the two asset example, where when you start

  • with two assets, the curve, the bullet

  • goes through the two assets.

  • In this case, with three or more assets,

  • it's going to turn out that the bullet is actually

  • going to include these assets as special cases,

  • but they won't be on the curve.

  • In other words, what this curve suggests

  • is that any rational person is going to want

  • to be on this upper branch.

  • What that means is that it never makes sense

  • to put all your money in one single security.

  • You see that?

  • In other words, if we agree that any rational investor is going

  • to want to be on that efficient frontier, that upper branch,

  • why would you ever want to be off of that branch?

  • You'd like to be Northwest of that, but you can't.

  • You'd never want to be below that branch,

  • or to the right of that branch because you could do better

  • by being on that branch.

  • So what this suggests is that we never

  • are going to want to hold 100% of IBM,

  • or 100% of General Motors, or 100% of Motorola.

  • If we did, we'd be on those dots,

  • and those dots would lie on that efficient frontier.

  • But in fact, they don't.

  • So right away, we have now departed

  • from Warren Buffett's world of, I want to pick a few stocks

  • and watch them very, very carefully.

  • Yeah, Brian?

  • AUDIENCE: Would you expand that to say that you'd never

  • want to invest in less than three stocks at a given time?

  • ANDREW LO: That's not necessarily true.

  • There are points on this line where--

  • and they may be pathological, so in other words,

  • they may be very rare--

  • but there may be points on the line

  • where you are holding two stocks, but not the third.

  • So you've got to be careful about that.

  • But those are exceptions.

  • As a generic statement, you're absolutely right.

  • The typical portfolio is going to have some of all three

  • of them.

  • And if you had four stocks, the typical portfolio

  • would have some of all four.

  • Yeah, [INAUDIBLE].

  • AUDIENCE: You answered my question,

  • which is if you take one more stock,

  • you'll always have your package [INAUDIBLE] n stocks include

  • all the [INAUDIBLE], all the n stocks so, at the limit

  • you should have an infinite number of stocks [INAUDIBLE]

  • ANDREW LO: Well, let me put it another way that may

  • be a little bit more intuitive.

  • What this diagram suggests-- you guys are already groping

  • towards--

  • is the insight that the more, the merrier.

  • As you add more stocks, you cannot make this investor worse

  • off.

  • So in other words, I've now shown you an example with three

  • stocks, we used to do two.

  • Is it possible that by giving you an extra stock

  • to invest in, I've made you worse off?

  • Yeah?

  • AUDIENCE: No

  • ANDREW LO: Why

  • AUDIENCE: Because you can just not invest in that stock.

  • ANDREW LO: Exactly.

  • I can never make you worse off in a world

  • where you're free to choose, that is.

  • Because you always have the option of getting

  • rid of the stock that you don't like.

  • You can always put 0 on it.

  • So to your point, [INAUDIBLE], as I add more stocks,

  • first of all my risk-reward trade-off

  • curve will get better.