Subtitles section Play video Print subtitles (instrumental piano music) - Many economists view financial markets as efficient with prices incorporating all available information about future values. Behavioral economists say that model simply doesn't reflect how markets actually work. So are markets efficient? Welcome to The Big Question, the monthly video series from Chicago Booth Review. I'm Hal Weitzman and I'm joined by an expert panel. Eugene Fama is the Robert R. McCormick Distinguished Service Professor of Finance at Chicago Booth. Well-known for his empirical analysis of asset prices and for developing the efficient market hypothesis, he was the joint recipient of the 2013 Nobel Prize in economic science, and Richard Thaler is the Charles R. Walgreen Distinguished Service Professor of Behavioral Science and Economics at Chicago Booth. He's director of Booth's center for decision research and co-author of the bestseller, Nudge. His most recent book is Misbehaving The Making of Behavioural Economics. Panel, welcome to The Big Question. Gene Fama, let me start with you. You came up with the efficient market hypothesis, so tell us briefly, what is it? - [Voiceover] Well, it's a very simple statement that prices reflect all available information. Testing the hypothesis turns out to be more difficult, but it's a simple hypothesis in principle. - Okay, Richard Thaler, do you agree that market prices reflect all available information? - Well. Like Gene says, it's easier to say than to test and I like to distinguish two aspects of it. One is whether you can beat the market, that's the one most people are most interested in, and the other is whether prices are correct, so if prices reflect all information, then they should land on the right price and we can separate those questions because they're different. - Okay, but the basic premise about the containing information is something you don't agree with then, it sounds like? - It's almost impossible to test that hypothesis. Except through the two questions that I've asked, can you beat the market and are prices right? - Okay, is that right, Gene Fama? If you say that prices reflect all available information, it necessarily means that a price is right at any particular point in time? - That's the statement of the hypothesis, but it's a model, it's not completely true, no models are completely true. They're approximations to the world, the question is, for what purposes are they a good approximation? As far as I'm concerned, they're a good approximation from almost every purpose. I don't know any investors who shouldn't be able if markets are efficient, for example, and there are all kinds of test with respect to the response of prices to specific kinds of information in which the hypothesis that prices adjust quickly to information looks very good. There are others that looks less good. So, it's a model, it's not entirely always true, but it's a good working model for most practical uses. - Okay, is that right, is it a good working model? - Well. I think for the first part, can you beat the market? I think Gene and I are in virtually complete agreement which is that's a good working hypothesis for any investor. - Does that mean you should assume, any individual investor should assume that markets are efficient? - Behave as if, would be the way you put it. - Well, behave as if. - Well, yeah, certainly, there's evidence going back to the thesis of Mike Jensen who was, I guess, I mean, one of Gene's first students, who was around at the same time, who did a thesis on whether mutual funds, on average, beat their benchmarks, and after they account for their fees, they don't, that was in the 60s, it's been updated a zillion times. You can quibble about exactly how to do it, but that's approximately true. So. Just investing based on fees is not a dumb thing to do regardless of the nuances that Gene and I might get into. - Okay, but you talked earlier about, in some cases, the model works, in other cases, it works less well. In your book, Richard Thaler, you talk about the 1987 crash, Black Monday, and you give that as an example of how prices are not right, the efficient markets don't really work. You say, "If prices are too variable, "they're in some sense wrong. "It's hard to argue the price at the close trading "on Thursday, October 15th, "and the price at the close of trading the following Monday, "more than 25% lower, can both be rational measures "of intrinsic value given the absence of news," but isn't the idea that efficient markets are supposed to be unpredictable? - Yes, but unpredictable doesn't mean rational. I have a two year old granddaughter who runs around like crazy, and I defy anyone to use a rational model to predict what she's gonna do next, so she will be unpredictable, but her behavior isn't well-captured by a model of maximizing anything other than what she calls fun. - So, does the market behave in the same way as your granddaughter? - Well, sometimes. I don't think anyone thinks that the value of the world economy fell 25% that day. Nothing happened. - So, if markets were efficient, there would be a certain bounded level of volatility? So, if-- - Well, in the absence... It's not a day when World War III was declared. - But it was a time where people were talking about, perhaps an oncoming recession which turned out not to happen, so in hindsight, this was a big mistake, but it needn't have been. So, in hindsight, every price is wrong. - Yeah. - That's 20/20 hindsight. - That's 20/20 hindsight, but what I would say is merely the big fluctuations that entire week. Two of the biggest up days in history occurred that week and three of the biggest down days and nothing was happening other than the fact that people were talking about how markets were going up and down like crazy all over the world, so that's one... indirect way that we can measure market efficiency. (coughs) This was essentially the approach that was pioneered by Bob Shiller, who Gene shared the Nobel Prize with, and his argument was prices fluctuate too much to be explained by a rational process. - Right, and Gene Fama, is that right? There's a certainly level at which prices just fluctuate too much? - Well, there's a test for that and the test says that when we look at longer periods of time, the variants of the price changes should not grow like the length of the time period. If there is all of this temporary variation in prices, that's not rational and, in fact, that does not indicate that there's temporary variation in prices, so you gotta kind of come up with a different test. Shiller's model was based on the proposition that there's no variation through time in expected returns, but we know there is a ton of variation in expected returns, so that kind of branch of testing, people lost interest in because you really can't come to any conclusions