Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • Good afternoon.

  • Today's speaker is Peter Thiel.

  • Peter, was the founder of PayPal, and

  • Palantir, and Founders Fund, and has invested in most of

  • the tech companies in Silicon Valley.

  • And he's going to talk about strategy and competition.

  • Thank you for coming, Peter. >> Awesome.

  • Thanks, Sam.

  • Thanks for inviting me.

  • Thanks for having me.

  • I sorta, I have a single a day

  • fixed that I'm completely obsessed with in.

  • On the business side which is that, if you're starting

  • a company, if you're the founder,

  • entrepreneur starting a company,

  • you always want to aim for

  • monopoly, and that you want to always avoid competition.

  • Hence, competition is for losers.

  • Something we'll be talking about today.

  • I'd like to start by saying something

  • about the basic idea of when you start one

  • of these companies how you go about, creating value?

  • And this question, what makes a business valuable?

  • And I wanna, suggest that there's basically,

  • a very simple very simple formula that

  • you, have a valuable company two things are true.

  • Number one, that it creates X dollars of value for

  • the world.

  • And number two, that you capture Y% of X.

  • And the critical thing that I think people always miss

  • in the sort of analysis is that X and y are completely

  • independent variables, and so X can be very big.

  • Y can be very small.

  • X can be of intermediate size.

  • And if Y is, is reasonably big you can still get

  • a very big business.

  • So, to create a valuable company you have to

  • basically, both create something of value and

  • capture some fraction of

  • the value of what you've created.

  • And sort of,

  • just to illustrate this is a contrast.

  • If you sorta, compare the US airline industry with

  • a company like Google on search.

  • If you sorta, measure by

  • the size of these industries you could, you could say

  • that airlines are still more important than search.

  • If you just measure it say by revenues.

  • There's 195 billion.

  • In domestic revenues in 2012.

  • Google had just north of 50 billion.

  • And certainly, sort of on some intuitive level,

  • if you said, if you were given a choice and

  • said well do you want to get rid of all air travel.

  • Or do you want to get rid of your ability to

  • use search engines?

  • The intuition would be that air travel is

  • something that's more important than search.

  • And this is, of course, just the domestic numbers.

  • If you had looked at this globally, airlines are much,

  • much bigger than search, or Google, is But

  • the profit margins are quite a bit less.

  • You know,

  • they were marginally profitable in 2012.

  • Think entire hundred year history of

  • the airline industry.

  • The cumulative profits in the U.S.

  • have been approximately zero.

  • The companies make money.

  • They episodically go bankrupt.

  • They get re-capitalized and

  • you sort of cycle and repeat.

  • And this is reflected in you know the combined market

  • capitalization of the airline industries maybe

  • something of the U.S. airline industry.

  • Something like a quarter that of Google.

  • So, you have a search engine much,

  • much smaller than air travel but much more valuable and

  • I think this reflects these very different valuations on

  • X and Y.

  • So, you know, if we look at perfect competition.

  • You know there are, sort of, there's some pros and

  • cons to the world of perfect competition.

  • On a high level it's always,

  • this is what you study in Econ One.

  • It's always, it's easy to model, which I think is why

  • Econ professors like talking about perfect competition.

  • It somehow is efficient, especially,

  • in a world where things are static because you have all

  • the consumer surplus gets captured by everybody.

  • And politically, it's what we're told is good in

  • our society, that you want to have competition and

  • this is somehow a good thing.

  • Of course, there are a lot of negatives.

  • It's generally not that good if you're.

  • You're involvement in anything that's

  • hyper-competitive because you often don't

  • make money off, come back to this a little bit later.

  • So, I think at one end of the spectrum you have

  • industries that are perfectly competitive.

  • And at the other end of the spectrum you have

  • things that, I would say, are monopolies.

  • And they're much stable, longer term businesses,

  • you have more capital.

  • And if you get a creative monopoly for

  • inventing something new, I think it's symptomatic of

  • having created something really valuable.

  • And so I do think this, the extreme binary view of

  • the world I always articulate is that

  • there are exactly two kinds of businesses in this world.

  • There are businesses that are perfectly competitive

  • and there are businesses that are monopolies.

  • And, there's shockingly little that is in between.

  • And this dichotomy is not understood very

  • well because people are constantly lying

  • about the nature of the businesses they're in.

  • And this is why,

  • this is in my mind, this is the most important.

  • It's not necessarily the most important thing in

  • business, but I think it's the most

  • important business idea that people don't understand.

  • That there are just these two kinds of businesses.

  • And so let me

  • say a little bit about the lies that people tell.

  • And so you basically, the basic, if you sort of

  • imagine that there was a spectrum of companies from

  • perfect competition to monopoly.

  • The apparent differences are quite small.

  • Because the people who have monopolies pretend not to.

  • They will basically say, and it's because you

  • don't want to get regulated by the government, you

  • don't want the government to come after you.

  • So you will never say that you have a monopoly.

  • So, anyone who has a monopoly will pretend that

  • they're in incredible competition.

  • And on the other end of the spectrum, if you

  • are incredibly competitive, and if you're in some sort

  • of business will you will never make any money.

  • You will be tempted to tell a lie that goes in

  • the other direction.

  • Where you will say that you're doing something

  • unique that is somehow less competitive than it looks.

  • Because you will want to differentiate, you

  • will want to track capital or something like that.

  • So, if the monopolists pretend not to have

  • a monopolies the non-monopolists pretend to

  • have monopolies.

  • The apparent difference is very small.

  • Where as the real difference I would submit is

  • actually quite big.

  • And so there's this distortion that happens

  • because of the lies people tell about their businesses.

  • And the lies are sort of in these opposite directions.

  • Let me, drill a little bit down further on the way

  • these lies work.

  • And so

  • the basic lie you tell as

  • a non-monopoly is that we're in a very small market.

  • The basic lie you tell as a monopoly is

  • that the market you're in is much bigger than it looks.

  • And so typically,

  • if you want to think this in sort of set theoretic terms.

  • You could say that a monopoly tells a why,

  • where you describe your business as the union of

  • these vastly different markets, and

  • the non-monopolies describes it as the intersection.

  • So, that in effect, if you're non-monopolist, you

  • will rhetorically describe your market as super small.

  • You're the only person in that market.

  • If you have monopoly, you'll describe it as super big,

  • and there's lots of competition in it.

  • So some examples of how this works in practice.

  • So I always use restaurants as the example of

  • a terrible business.

  • And there's always, sort of, ideas