Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • Hi everyone.

  • Thank you so much for welcoming me and Joe here, today.

  • We're really excited to be here this afternoon to talk about Universal Basic Income, or UBI.

  • And, we think it's important to talk about this, because UBI is a big idea that has the

  • potential to transform how we, as a community of effective altruists, donors, infomentors,

  • and researchers think about doing good in the world.

  • So, I'll start us off today by introducing UBI and, sort of, the debate about its effectiveness,

  • and discussing how existing evidence from RCTs can help inform how we think about this

  • debate.

  • And then I'll hand it over to Joe, who will talk about some ongoing UBI research, and

  • wrap up with some thoughts and questions about what this means for all of us as effective

  • altruists.

  • So, if you've kept up with the development economics news over the past year or so, you've

  • probably heard a lot of buzz about UBI.

  • As a reminder, UBI is a cash-transfer that is, as the name implies, universal, meaning

  • that all people in a given area receive it.

  • It is not targeted at specific populations, and there are no conditions placed on how

  • the money may be used.

  • The transfer is regularly recurring, delivered over the long term, and sufficient to meet

  • basic needs.

  • And around the world, there are studies taking place to better understand the various iterations

  • of UBI, and its potential impacts.

  • So, what explains the widespread interest in UBI today?

  • On the one hand, in many countries like the US, the economy is being rapidly transformed

  • by technology.

  • Automation is getting cheaper and better every day.

  • According to one study by economists at MIT and Boston University, the number - each robot

  • that came into the world between 1993 and 2007 reduced the number of available jobs

  • by 5.6 So, automation has already displaced, and likely will continue to displace workers,

  • especially in certain industries.

  • This makes UBI a potentially attractive policy option, for those who are concerned about

  • the wellbeing of workers left behind by automation and technology advances.

  • On the other hand, while the world has made large strides in reducing poverty, more than

  • 700 million people still live on less than $1.90 per day.

  • And especially in low income countries where the extreme poor live, UBI is seen as a potential

  • policy option to help bring adults and children up to the poverty line, and ensure that their

  • basic needs are met.

  • In high and low countries alike, there are often concerns about the effectiveness of

  • existing social safety net programs.

  • People wonder if current programs are as effective as they could be.

  • They might stigmatize recipients.

  • They might be ineffectively delivered.

  • And, with the proliferation of the gig economy and alternative work arrangements, employer-based

  • approaches to social welfare, like many of those that we have in place today, may not

  • be suitable going forward.

  • Like any potentially disruptive new approach, of course there are supporters and detractors

  • of UBI.

  • Supporters argue that UBI might be more efficient than existing social programs, that its unconditional

  • nature offers recipients flexibility and autonomy, and that new technology makes it more feasible

  • than ever to distribute basic income transfers.

  • On the other hand, detractors raise concerns about UBI simply being too costly to be a

  • reasonable solution, and they also raise concerns about how unconditional cash may be used by

  • recipients.

  • And of course, despite new technology, the infrastructure to receive payments may not

  • exist in all contexts, especially those where the most poor live.

  • So there are valid points on both sides of this debate.

  • How can we, as effective altruists, decide where to put our weight as a community, and

  • what more do we need to know?

  • So, let's look at some existing evidence.

  • First, on the concern that receiving cash with no conditions attached might lead to

  • a reduction in work.

  • On average, there is evidence that that is not the case.

  • What about concerns that cash given with few or no strings attached will be squandered?

  • In Kenya, researchers tested a program implemented by GiveDirectly, which transferred money in

  • a lump sum to poor households, and they found that it led to increases in both economic

  • and non-economic wellbeing, and did not lead to increases in spending on temptation goods

  • like alcohol or tobacco.

  • What's important to note is that these outcomes were measured less than a year after the transfer

  • was given, and if we're trying to understand cash transfers as a way to reduce poverty,

  • and if we're trying to think about them as a way to inform our opinions about UBI, we

  • should probably consider the longer-term effects.

  • So, we have some research on that as well.

  • Researchers in Uganda and Sri Lanka have found that unsupervised cash grants, distributed

  • in sort of a business setting, had positive impacts on business investment, profits, and

  • household income after 4 or 5 years.

  • But I just mentioned that those were given in a business setting.

  • In Uganda, the grants were given to groups of young people who had submitted business

  • plans.

  • And in Sri Lanka, grants were given to micro-enterprise owners.

  • And if we want to understand the relevance of cash transfers for UBI, we might want to

  • think about cash without this framing or context attached to it.

  • So to shed some light on that question, we can turn back to the study that researchers

  • did of GiveDirectly's program in Kenya.

  • The researchers, Johannes Haushofer and Jeremy Shapiro, simply released longer-term results

  • from that cash transfer, and you might have seen a lot of blogs on the internet, a lot

  • of tweets that have been talking about these results.

  • They've generated a lot of discussion.

  • And overall, the results were largely ambiguous, mostly due to some methodology challenges

  • of the kind that plague many research studies.

  • This includes differential attrition rates between the households who did receive transfers

  • and who didn't, and some others that I'm happy to talk about in office hours tomorrow if

  • you're interested.

  • Even though the results were pretty ambiguous, they're still an important input into the

  • broader evidence landscape around cash transfers and UBI.

  • And, luckily, GiveDirectly is doing many other RCTs and many other studies whose results

  • will continue to inform this discussion.

  • So, when GiveDirectly and the researchers started the study, they designed the evaluation

  • to answer some really important policy questions.

  • They assigned households to three different groups, and that allowed them to figure out

  • what happens to people who receive cash, people whose neighbors receive cash, and people whose

  • communities are not exposed to cash at all.

  • After looking at the three-year survey results, the researchers found that most of those positive

  • impacts that I mentioned after 9 months had disappeared.

  • Households who had received the cash transfers did have more assets, but the impacts on consumption,

  • investment, and happiness were no longer apparent.

  • And there's also some suggestive evidence that households whose neighbors received cash,

  • but who didn't receive cash themselves, experienced negative spillover effects, but again, this

  • evidence is subject to some methodological questions, and we'll want to have more research

  • on this question in the future.

  • And, Joe is going to tell you about some of the efforts that are currently ongoing to

  • get more evidence on these questions in a little bit.

  • But before he does, I want to return to one of the motivations behind UBI, which is reducing

  • poverty.

  • We're not yet sure if basic income will lead to a sustainable income to economic or non-economic

  • wellbeing of the households living in extreme poverty.

  • But while we wait for results, there is already evidence on one approach, which is targeted

  • to households living on less than $1.90 a day.

  • That can sustainably improve livelihoods.

  • It's called the graduation approach, and it was initially designed and tested by BRAC,

  • which is an NGO in Bangaladesh.

  • At its heard, the graduation approach gives a transfer of a productive asset, which is

  • meant to be the core of a small business.

  • And it also includes other complementary services, including coaching and consumption support,

  • usually in the form of cash transfers.

  • This is an actively managed program, in which households receive two years of support.

  • JPAL-affiliated researchers have evaluated the program in Bangaladesh and in 6 other

  • countries around the world, and found that overall the program had positive impacts on

  • most measures of economic and non-economic wellbeing, both when the program ended, and

  • a year later, after all the program support had ended.

  • And in two sites, where it's been tested four years later - so, 7 years after the asset

  • was transferred originally - there's evidence that consumption, income, assets, and psychosocial

  • well-being all continued to improve.

  • Which suggests that the changes caused by this approach have lasting power.

  • Obviously, a program that involves all of these components is more expensive and more

  • hands-on than delivering cash alone.

  • So, researchers and implementers alike are really interested in figuring out whether

  • it can be delivered in a less intensive version, or with fewer components.

  • And, in Ghana, researchers tested just the asset transfer alone, and in Uganda, researchers

  • tested a cash transfer that was roughly equal to the cost of delivering a sort of streamlined

  • version of this program.

  • And in both cases, they found that this sort of capital-infusion alone did not have the

  • same positive effects on consumption, investment, or asset ownership.

  • So, there seems to be something about the full package of the program that impacts households

  • differently than capital alone can.

  • So what does this mean, going back to the question of basic income?

  • One interpretation is that households who are living in extreme poverty in lower and

  • middle income countries face a number of pervasive market failures, like limited access to capital,

  • limited information, and low trust in market institutions.

  • The full package of graduation seems to be able to mitigate some of these market failures,

  • in a way that cash alone may not be able to.

  • So, in these contexts, we still need more evidence on whether cash transfers that are

  • sufficiently large, or delivered in sufficiently long duration, can overcome some of these

  • barriers that existing evidence - that I just mentioned - have not been able to.

  • And it also raises interesting questions about cash transfers in high income countries like

  • the US.

  • Here, the market failures I just mentioned are likely to be less pervasive, and less

  • complex than they are in the countries where we're trying to reduce extreme poverty.

  • But of course, we still need more research across contexts, to understand what impact

  • something like a UBI will have on the household to receive it.

  • With that, I will hand it over to Joe, to talk about some of that work.

  • Alright.

  • Joe Huston, originally from San Antonio, is the CFO at GiveDirectly, a nonprofit which

  • is devoted exclusively to delivering unconditional cash transfers to the extreme poor.

  • Prior to heading GiveDirectly's finance function, he spent three years managing their operations

  • in Kenya and Uganda, where he led the launch of GiveDirectly's 21,000 person experimental

  • evaluation of universal basic income in that country.

  • Previously, he worked at US asset management firm Bridgewater Associates, and earned a

  • BA in Economics from Dartmouth College.

  • Please welcome Joe Huston.

  • I'll start with saying that I'm really glad to be here.

  • I originally found GiveDirectly through the effective altruism community, and so conversations

  • like these are very near and dear to my heart.

  • I also know that there's a bunch of sort of different topics to dig into.

  • UBI in the developed world, the three-year results from Kenya, and so I'll try to keep

  • it brief so we have time for conversation, but we'll see how well I keep the promise.

  • And so, a kind of core piece to start out with, when we're thinking about "How would

  • a universal basic income be different from some of the other things we already know about

  • cash transfers" gets into what's unique about a universal basic income - that particular

  • structure of cash transfer.

  • Well, it's a few things.

  • First, it's universal.

  • So, whole communities are receiving the cash transfer, relative to targeting specific income

  • levels or specific levels of vulnerability.

  • What that also means is that you have a lot of variation in the types of recipient.

  • It's not just business owners or people in extreme poverty, but you have some variation

  • in terms of just, whatever the communities look like.

  • The second thing is that it's a particular amount: it's basic.

  • It's sufficient to cover basic needs, and so that also sort of differs from some of

  • what we already know about other sorts of cash transfer studies, which might be smaller,

  • or big, one-time capital grants.

  • It's a particular size of cash transfer.

  • And the third thing is that it's an income.

  • It should be something you can rely on for your entire life, to sort of provide a permanent

  • cash floor, so that you're always up to a certain standard of living, because you're

  • receiving a cash transfer equal to the cost of that standard of living.

  • And so relative to cash transfer programs, that are one-time grants, like what Haushofer

  • and Shapiro studied, or targeted towards a particular life stage: a pension, or support

  • for people who have kids in secondary school.

  • The idea behind a universal basic income should be something that sort of follows you for

  • your entire life, and provides long-term cash support.

  • So what do we know about that type of cash transfer?

  • Well, you know in general from what Sam told you, is that there's a lot of studies of cash

  • transfers broadly.

  • Literally over 100 studies on cash transfers all over the world.

  • There are a handful of studies that get grouped in specifically about universal basic income.

  • In the 60s and 70s, there was a wave of experiments in the US and Canada that tested a variant

  • of a universal basic income called a negative income tax.

  • From those - they typically weren't universal, they were targeted towards the poor.

  • The experiments also weren't universal because there was sort of a lottery-like system, choosing

  • people randomly to participate in the studies.

  • So you didn't sort of get the community level of facts.

  • They were large, and so they were basic, usually.

  • They provided a meaningful level of support.

  • But they also weren't typically long-term.

  • Usually sort of a few years or so.

  • What you saw from those studies is similar to what you see in a lot of the cash studies.

  • First, people got money, and so they were mechanically less poor.

  • And then you saw that flow through to sort of broad base improvements.

  • You saw educational attainment increase.

  • In Canada, you saw hospitalization rates fall pretty markedly.

  • One thing that's different from the Developed World studies that doesn't show up in the

  • Developing World studies, is that you did see modest reductions in work effort.

  • But where those showed up, they were showing up in populations where you might be more

  • okay with working less.

  • They showed up in teenagers, who worked less and went to school more, and young mothers,

  • just after giving birth.

  • And so you might sort of be okay with those populations working a little bit less.

  • Otherwise, there's a handful of studies in Namibia and Maja Pradesh in India, that looked

  • at universal - these universal cash transfers.

  • But, in Namibia it wasn't a randomized controlled trial, and didn't last for very long: only

  • a couple of years.

  • And in India, where they did use that experimental approach, it similarly didn't last all that

  • long.

  • Then, recently, as you've probably seen in the news, there's been an explosion of studies,

  • basically all over the world.

  • GiveDirectly has launched one in Kenya, there's one in Finland, there's one in the Netherlands.

  • There's been demonstration projects like this one in Germany, called My Basic Income.

  • And there's one coming up in Stockton, California as well.

  • And there's sort of been two larger randomized controlled trials that are coming onboard.

  • First, in Ontario, done by the provincial government there.

  • And by YCombinator in California.

  • Because these studies are expensive, researchers have typically made cost-benefit calculations

  • to prioritize what they're studying.

  • And so, almost none of these have been universal, in the sense of looking at whole communities.

  • The YCombinator one isn't looking at whole communities, but they are looking at some

  • income variation, and so they are doing their sort of best to balance those types of things.

  • And then, typically, they haven't gone that far out in terms of long-term, which might

  • sort of give you a question about whether that matters or not in interpreting these

  • studies.

  • GiveDirectly sort of took the approach of trying to design a study that would complement

  • this body of research, as well as the body of research about cash transfers broadly.

  • And so, the study is randomized at the village level.

  • And so, whole communities will be treated differently, with about 44 villages receiving

  • 12 years of monthly payments - about $23 - sized to sort of meet the poverty line in rural

  • Kenya.

  • That group of villages will be compared against villages receiving 2 years worth of basic

  • income payments, and a group of villages receiving one-time cash grants of about $500 per adult.That's

  • roughly equal to the sum of those 2 years worth of payments.

  • And then all three of those groups will be compared to a control group.

  • The research is being led by development economists, like Abhijit Banerjee, who founded JPAL, and

  • Tavneet Suri, who is also director at JPAL, as well as Alan Krueger, who is the former

  • chair of the Council of Economic Advisors for President Obama, to kind of bridge the

  • policy worlds across the developing and developed world.

  • And the actual research surveying itself is being done by Innovations for Poverty Action,

  • and we should have results out early next year, which is actually when we'll have an

  • explosion of results out from GiveDirectly, Canada, and Finland as well.

  • With this type of study, you sort of want to look at a broad set of outcome variables.

  • And so we're looking at both individual level outcome variables, in terms of earning or

  • spending or assets, occupations and time-use, gender relations and risk-taking.

  • Sort of at the individual level, how do those things evolve?

  • We're also looking at community level effects, because there's something unique about this

  • type of cash transfer, that everyone in society - or at least most of the people you're seeing

  • day-to-day, are also receiving that cash transfer.

  • And so we're looking at things like community level economic effects, access to health or

  • education or water facilities, how things like community or political engagement evolve,

  • as well as how crime levels change.

  • And then we'll look at both of those types of things based off of the differences in

  • the cash transfers.

  • How it varies between the 12 year group of villages, and the 2 year group, which should

  • help inform how we should think about the other studies, that are relatively shorter

  • term, as well as the structure of how cash grants achieve different goals or different

  • outcomes versus the recurring stream payments.

  • And then, because it's universal, we have a rich set of data of different types of people

  • receiving a cash transfer, and then seeing if they spend it different.

  • So we'll get to see how - how do different starting income groups spend cash differently?

  • How do different age groups, or genders, spend cash differently?

  • Which should help inform broader policy questions beyond just a UBI.

  • And so, how should the effective altruist community think about this?

  • And I'll apologize - the slides got merged and the formatting got a bit weird.

  • I think there's a few different types of questions the community should answer.

  • The first one is, what do we think the bet is, in terms of the direct impact of these

  • cash transfers.

  • And for this, we have a rich data of other types of cash transfers, from literally all

  • over the world, where, if you give cash to people who don't have it, they are immediately

  • a little bit less poor, because they have cash, and you start to see that flow through

  • into broader wellbeing things, things like increased consumption, or increased assets

  • and earnings.

  • You also see it show up in more indirect things, like stress or psychological wellbeing.

  • In Malawi, you saw women whose families received small, recurring payments get pregnant later,

  • marry later, and have lower rates of HIV, because they had a little bit more security

  • in society.

  • And so, part of the bet on effective altruism, is a bet on how it'll differ from other types

  • of cash transfers.

  • Which we can maybe dig into in the Q&A.

  • The second bet for the community, is about what the sort of broader policy impact of

  • this type of study will be.

  • And this applies to any of the - I think it's not 12 studies GiveDirectly is doing.

  • And so, to give you one example of what the policy potential of the universal basic income

  • study, this is taken from an estimate by the government of India, where they looked at

  • how - sort of modeling out how, if they replaced existing subsidy programs that they maintain

  • with a modest universal basic income of cash support provided, essentially universally,

  • what that would do to poverty in India.

  • And what they estimated was that it would take it from about 22% to 0.45%.

  • Literally bringing over 100 million people out of poverty, basically immediately.

  • That doesn't necessarily mean that that's what we should do: there's an opportunity

  • cost for that type of spending.

  • There might be other effects of the cash transfer that are worth studying.

  • But it gives you a sense of the potential scale of the policy implications of this type

  • of research, beyond the 21,000 people who are receiving cash from GiveDirectly.

  • The third, I think bet - or question - for the effective altruism community, is a more

  • foundational one.

  • And I think for that, to start with, it's useful looking at the process that I think

  • we mostly apply, at least for effective altruism, to help existing poor people today.

  • Where it looks like choosing a set of outcomes that we think are important - maybe it's earnings,

  • or health, or how long your life is or something like that - choosing goods and services that

  • we think would improve those outcomes, whether it's a graduation program or a deworming pill,

  • or a goat, and then choosing providers who we think can deliver those goods and services

  • as best they can.

  • And I think a lot of what the community is focused on is doing this process better than

  • how aid and development have traditionally done it before.

  • What I think is helpful about cash transfers is they pose a more foundational question

  • of who should make these choices, what types of outcomes are important, whether it's - how

  • you value earnings, or not getting rained on, or being a little bit extra healthy.

  • How you value improvements in the lives of your children.

  • The existing status quo is, donors and funders start with a pool of money, and almost by

  • virtue of that, they become the choosers of these next three things.

  • But cash transfers literally put the budget in charge of the people we're trying to help,

  • and lets them make those choices.

  • I think that switch of power is important, in part just because of practical reasons.

  • There's a tale of two track records where the poor have literally,over 100 studies backing

  • up the quality of their decision making when they control the budget.

  • And then, the funders, implementers, have whatever you think about the last 50 years

  • of development history.

  • I think the second one is that it's a genuinely tricky problem to figure out what types of

  • outcomes matter.

  • In part, people are very, very different.

  • We see GiveDirectly recipients buy an incredible, diverse array of things.

  • Whether it's solar panels, or livestock, or roofs.

  • We saw someone start a band.

  • There's an incredible diversity in humans.

  • And that's amplified by the fact that most of the decision making is done by people in

  • San Francisco or New York, or DC, or London.

  • And it's on behalf of people who are living in places like rural Western Kenya.

  • And I think doing that type of calculation, which we can try to do better, as effective

  • altruists, is inherently very, very difficult.

  • Which is not to say that the entire portfolio should shift towards recipient-chosen, or

  • recipient-decided, but existing portfolios are extremely skewed.

  • Basically, any way you cut it, whether you look at humanitarian aid, or institutional

  • aid given by governments, or US international charitable giving, basically the whole pots

  • of money meant to help the poor are decided by the rich.

  • Which is a sort of unintuitive result, given what we've talked about before.

  • So I think one of the most helpful things that cash transfers can do, with UBI being

  • an example of that, is force the effective altruism community to answer that more foundational

  • question of who should decide which outcomes matter, and what types of goods and services

  • best achieve those outcomes.

  • Thank you.

  • Alright.

  • Great jobs guys.

  • Few minutes for questions, and of course, the app, the website, go ahead and submit.

  • Maybe just to start off with a couple of things that I could use a little help in filling

  • in my understanding.

  • Negative spillovers when some people in the village get money and others don't: what does

  • that look like?

  • I don't have an intuition for - how does somebody's life get worse in that situation?

  • Yeah, so, the researchers have done a little bit of work to try to understand what this

  • means.

  • There's one paper that they've released, which finds that there might be some negative implications

  • on people's wellbeing.

  • So, people might feel more stressed or depressed, if their neighbor is receiving cash and they

  • aren't.

  • In the 2018 paper, which is the 3 year results that I mentioned, the researchers posit that

  • households that didn't receive cash were selling off assets, and so they were - they owned

  • fewer assets.

  • And then households who did receive cash, as I mentioned, had more assets at the end.

  • So, feel free to add, Joe, but that's...

  • Yeah.

  • I think the 3 year study is one that's genuinely hard to interpret, because of the methodological

  • things which we can dig into.

  • It's a tricky study to synthesize and know what to do about, which is part of why - in

  • 2014 we launched a study specifically geared to answering this question in a high-quality

  • way.

  • The question of how do non-recipients of cash get impacted by being near recipients of cash.

  • So that we randomized the concentration of cash transfer delivered in different regions.

  • So that you can really highlight how people are affected.

  • And that'll have results out something like August or September this year.

  • I think the other question for the effective altruism community is how those results, in

  • part, inform research design, about how you should approach individually randomized studies

  • where people are very close.

  • For GiveDirectly's programming, we've moved very, very far away from choosing out individuals

  • from communities.

  • In general, we've moved much more towards enrolling almost everyone.

  • That's literally the case for the UBI study, but even for our day-to-day programming, we're

  • moving much towards saturating villages.

  • And so it's a little bit harder to know, without seeing the other study, which will look across

  • villages as well, how to draw the right conclusions from that 3 year study for what we do today.

  • Another just kind of clarification question.

  • When you mention the graduation program, the concept of asset transfer, I'm picturing a

  • cow.

  • Is that the right image for me to have in mind?

  • Yeah, so the graduation program is always tailored to whatever context where it's being

  • implemented.

  • Usually it's livestock, but it can also be supplies to open up a small shop and sell

  • berets, or makeup, or cigarettes, whatever makes sense for the community.

  • Cool.

  • Questions coming in.

  • One just about the challenges of running a study that's going to go on for 12 years.

  • Things are going to change in the world around you.

  • I mean, it's always hard to hold things constant, but, in that span of time, it gets even more

  • difficult.

  • How do you think about those challenges?

  • Yeah, it's tricky.

  • You have to guess what you think your follow-up call center will cost in 2029, or whatever.

  • Figure out how to manage the cash between Kenyan banks and US banks, to maintain a sort

  • of standard payment across those 12 years.

  • Think about how to increase it with inflation.

  • It's a bunch of really hard questions, that we're trying to be pretty paranoid about,

  • in terms of playing out different scenarios.

  • If GiveDirectly got shut down in Kenya for whatever reason, could we continue payments

  • if we wanted to?

  • And things like that.

  • It had a bunch of specific answers to those little questions, but it required a lot of

  • - a decent amount of work.

  • The nice thing is once you get past this hurdle - we've now enrolled the 21,000 people - it's

  • a little bit more steady state.

  • The picture looks like: once a month we send on payments, and people receive text messages,

  • and then once every few months we have our call center call them.

  • And so that's a much lighter run rate engagement, that we have to keep up for the next decade

  • or so.

  • And so that piece of it is a lot easier than the initial lift to get all those people enrolled.

  • We're a little bit over time already, so this will have to be the last question, but, when

  • you think about the tradeoffs between a negative income tax and the universal basic income,

  • one person is asking, why give the universal basic income to everyone?

  • Those that don't need it, it seems wasteful.

  • How about the universal - not the universal - how about the non-universal negative income

  • tax, as an alternative?

  • Yeah.

  • One thing I should note is, you can achieve pretty similar distributions of incomes post-tax,

  • as in post-transfers, with either negative income tax or UBI.

  • Because with a UBI, if you give Bill Gates his $12,000 a year, you end up taxing it back.

  • And so you can end up with the same distributions for both settings.

  • I think the tradeoffs become in part political: what's more palatable?

  • Where in one case it's easier to say, let's give cash to the poor.

  • Where in another case it might be easier to get people on board with a universal support,

  • that's, everyone's dividend is part of being in society.

  • Other people also argue, which I'm looking forward to seeing, that there's something

  • helpful about the cash support being universal, so that it's not stigmatizing.

  • That it's not just the dole for the poor.

  • If it's less that and more a universal floor for everybody, you might think that in part

  • politically it's easier to maintain, but also maybe it has different effects.

  • That people don't view it as, because I'm poor I get this support, but because I'm part

  • of society I don't deserve to starve.

  • And that may have different sorts of effects in terms of how it's spent.

  • Or maybe that it's spent more communally.

  • And so I think those are the things we'll try to test.

  • Cool.

  • Unfortunately we are out of time.

  • We do have a couple of announcements coming up.

  • But first, how about another round of applause for Sam Carter and Joe Huston?

  • Thank you very much, guys.

Hi everyone.

Subtitles and vocabulary

Click the word to look it up Click the word to find further inforamtion about it