Subtitles section Play video
-
Jacob: Welcome to Crash Course Economics, my name is Jacob Clifford
-
Adriene: and I’m Adriene Hill. Today we’re going to talk about monopolies! Which are
-
terrible, illegal, and only serve to exploit helpless consumers, except when they’re
-
delivering essential services that competitive free markets kind of fail to deliver.
-
Jacob: So, are monopolies are good? Or bad? Or?
-
Adriene: Both.
-
[Theme Music]
-
Jacob: When some people hear the word “capitalist” they picture the robber barons of the 19th century.
-
Cutthroat monopolists, like Andrew Carnegie, JP Morgan, and John D. Rockefeller.
-
They dominated industries like oil, railroads, banking, & steel and would do anything to crush their competitors.
-
After all, in Rockefeller’s words “The growth of a large business is merely a survival of the fittest.”
-
Now, it’s true that market economists love competition, but monopolies are the antithesis of competition.
-
In most cases, economists want to prevent monopolies, not celebrate them. Let’s go to the Thought Bubble:
-
Adriene: A pure monopoly is a market controlled by one seller with a good or service that
-
has no close substitutes. But the true power of a monopoly comes from its ability to keep
-
competitors out of the market. Monopolies are able to erect obstacles that economists
-
call barriers to entry. If a company starts offering a brand new product in a market with
-
low barriers, they won’t maintain market power for very long.
-
Take gourmet food trucks. In the last decade, gourmet cooks started moving into the street
-
food business, competing in a market historically associated with lower-quality options like
-
hot dog vendors. These food trucks were a hit. Demand was high and the barriers to entry
-
were relatively low, so more and more competitors jumped in. Now food trucks are kind of everywhere.
-
And that’s exactly how capitalism is supposed to work. People wanted more street food options and profit-
-
seeking entrepreneurs gave them what they wanted. Incentives and competition made society better off.
-
But imagine a city where there are a limited number of licenses for food trucks, and I
-
own all of them for my fleet of artisanal macaroni and cheese trucks. I also know the
-
mayor, since he’s a big fan of artisanal macaroni and cheese. If I can convince the
-
mayor to ban traditional push cart food vendors, with their shwarma and their bacon-wrapped
-
hot dogs, I’ll have a monopoly on street food.
-
I’m not increasing profit by producing more stuff. I’ve influenced government regulations
-
in such a way that anyone who’s hungry, but doesn’t want to enter a building, has
-
to buy food from me. This is sometimes called crony capitalism, and it’s a big reason
-
many economists call for government transparency and accountability.
-
Jacob: Thanks Thought Bubble. Companies don’t have to have a literal monopoly to exercise monopoly power.
-
When a single company has a huge market share in its industry, like Google does in search,
-
they wield a lot of the same power that a pure monopoly would.
-
Now, when few firms have a large majority of market share, it’s called an oligopoly.
-
The market for mobile device operating systems is a good example with Google’s Android and Apple's iOS.
-
The point is that one company doesn’t need to have 100% market shares to operate like a monopoly.
-
In the example of the anti-food-truck ordinance, the barrier to entry was government regulation,
-
but what some other ways companies maintain large market shares?
-
Well, there’s also control of resources, like DeBeers once had 90% of market share
-
in diamonds because they controlled the world’s diamond mines.
-
Another barrier is high start up costs. You may want to build a nuclear power plant to
-
compete with your power company but you need a whole lot of money to get in the game.
-
Adriene: Monopolies can restrict output and charge higher prices without worrying about
-
competitors. This is why most economists support anti-trust laws that promote competition and
-
outlaw anticompetitive tactics.
-
They’re called antitrust laws because monopolies used to be called “trusts”. In 1890, the
-
US passed the Sherman Act, named for Senator John Sherman. Sherman argued, “If we will
-
not endure a king as a political power we should not endure a king over the production,
-
transportation, and sale of any of the necessaries of life.”
-
The Sherman Act outlaws any monopolization or attempted monopolization. Court rulings and later laws
-
gave the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission greater authority to prevent monopoles.
-
If the Coca Cola company wanted to purchase PepsiCo, it’d be a tough regulatory sell.
-
In the US mergers and acquisitions need to be approved by the government agencies.
-
Economists call the act of buying companies that produce similar products horizontal integration.
-
Like, AT&T tried to buy T-Mobile, but failed because regulators believed the new company
-
would control too big a share of the wireless communications market.
-
Vertical integration, on the other hand, is when a company directly owns or controls its supply chain.
-
For example, in the 1920s, the Ford Motor Company owned much of the entire
-
supply chain needed to make cars. It owned iron and coal mines, and made its own steel,
-
glass, tires, and even paper in the massive River Rouge factory complex in Michigan.
-
Vertical integration is complicated, and it’s not always illegal. When a company just expands
-
its business to insource part of its supply chain, that’s usually not subject to antitrust regulation.
-
Companies can run into some trouble when they try to vertically integrate via mergers.
-
Antitrust regulations can also prevent companies from making anticompetitive deals with their suppliers.
-
In the late 1990s, Microsoft was accused of pressuring PC manufacturers to pre-install
-
Microsoft’s web browser, Internet Explorer, and exclude their main browser competitor, Netscape.
-
Regulators busted them, and almost busted up the company.
-
Even Toys R Us! It’s gotten in trouble for conspiring with toy suppliers, like Hasbro
-
and Mattel, to stop the manufacturers from selling certain toys to other stores.
-
So monopolies and monpolistic behavior are bad, right? Well, it turn out that sometimes
-
they’re useful. Look at patents. A patent grants an inventor exclusive rights to profit
-
from a specific product or process.
-
In the US, it is actually written into the Constitution. Patents and other intellectual property rights
-
encourage innovation. Pharmaceutical companies spend billions of dollars each year developing drugs,
-
and patents allow them to recover those research and development costs and, ideally, earn profit.
-
A patent essentially guarantees their right to be a monopoly, but not forever.
-
After a certain amount of time, usually about 20 years, a patent expires, which lowers the barriers to entry.
-
Competition moves in, prices fall, and companies look for something new to patent.
-
Intellectual property law and patents are really complex. And Stan, he’s actually done a whole series about 'em.
-
Jacob: Natural monopolies are special situations where it is more cost effective to have one
-
large producer rather than several smaller competing firms.
-
The best examples are public utilities in markets such as electricity, water, natural
-
gas, and sewage. They may be privately owned or publicly owned but either way, they remain
-
a monopoly because the government limits competition.
-
I mean, if there were three competing electric power companies in one city, that would mean
-
building three different power plants, and running three sets of power lines through the streets.
-
The result would be higher costs. So, in this case, it would be cheaper to have one
-
electric company because they have economies of scale. The monopoly can still raise prices
-
and abuse its position, so the government often regulates prices and fees.
-
Now, of course there are debates over when the government should interfere and which
-
markets justify natural monopolies.
-
Nike has about 90% market share in basketball shoes, but it’s not a natural monopoly.
-
It’s a non-coercive monopoly. There are plenty of other shoe manufacturers and people
-
aren’t forced to buy Nike shoes. So there’s no reason for the government to get involved.
-
But that’s not always the case. Up to the 1970s AT&T was given natural monopoly status,
-
which gave it nearly complete control of the telephone industry.
-
In 1974 an antitrust lawsuit was filed by the Department of Justice, and the end result
-
was the largest corporate breakup in American history. AT&T dissolved in seven regional
-
telephone companies, and other companies like Sprint and MCI quickly jumped into the market.
-
This process called deregulation, and it’s happened in many markets from delivering mail to airlines.
-
Adriene: So let’s step back, here. Why are so worried about monopolies? Well, a lot of this has to do with pricing.
-
For one, monopolies can charge more for their products than they could if the market was competitive.
-
They can also engage in a practice called price discrimination. Price discrimination
-
is the practice of charging different consumers different prices for exactly the same product.
-
In fact the earliest regulation of railroads came about because they were engaged in price discrimination.
-
They charged different rates to haul freight. This gave an advantage to
-
companies that shipped more freight and helped to force smaller producers out of business,
-
creating even more monopoly power in the economy.
-
But price discrimination isn’t just for monopolies, and it’s not always illegal.
-
To pull off price discrimination, a business needs to be able to segregate the market
-
based on consumers’ willingness to pay.
-
The airline industry does this using time: charging those that book early less than those that book late.
-
A price-sensitive student might only be able to pay $200 so she books a seat weeks or months in advance.
-
A time-sensitive businesswoman that needs to be at a board meeting tomorrow,
-
might be willing to pay $800 for that same type of seat on the same flight.
-
The point is, charging a single price wouldn’t generate as much profit as charging different prices.
-
Price discrimination happens more often than you might think.
-
Discounts based on age or occupation are good examples.
-
Price discrimination works best when firms have a large share of market power.
-
If there were hundreds of airlines it is unlikely that any one of them could price discriminate without losing customers.
-
Like a lot of things we look at here at Crash Course, monopolies and pricing are complicated.
-
Generally, competition is a good thing. Except when it isn’t. Thanks for watching. We’ll see you next week.
-
Crash Course Economics is made with the help of all these fine people. You can support
-
Crash Course at Patreon. Patreon is a voluntary subscription service where your donations
-
help keep Crash Course free, for everyone, forever.
-
Thanks so much for letting us monopolize your time for the last ten minutes or so.