Placeholder Image

Subtitles section Play video

  • [SQUEAKING]

  • [RUSTLING]

  • [CLICKING]

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Welcome to lecture three.

  • Today and on Wednesday, we're going

  • to talk about time preferences and particular theory.

  • We're going to talk a lot about a lot of applications,

  • a lot of applications that are sort of close

  • to your real world, including procrastination of problem

  • sets, all sorts of other choices such as credit card debt,

  • and so on, and so forth.

  • Can you be a little quiet?

  • Thank you.

  • Think of the lectures today and on Wednesday

  • building some framework and some sort of structure

  • and how to think about these things.

  • It's a little drier than maybe other lectures, in part

  • because it's about theory, and about writing down a model,

  • and trying to think about the world.

  • Partially we're doing that to sort of try

  • to explain behaviors that we see in the world,

  • partially we do that because at the end,

  • we try to think about welfare and how

  • to evaluate certain outcomes-- is

  • that good or bad-- certain policies and things to do,

  • which later in the course we're going to talk about.

  • But for that you, need some structure

  • how to think about some of those things.

  • At the heart of it, a lot of this

  • is about procrastination, about choices between the present

  • and the future.

  • Your problem set, in part, is also about procrastination.

  • It will be posted later today, probably late.

  • Please do let us know if you have any questions.

  • As I said, please be on time.

  • Do the readings.

  • There will be random pop quizzes.

  • They will be at the beginning of the class,

  • so you should be on time.

  • The laptop section is still over there.

  • If you want to use your laptop, it should be there, ideally,

  • in the front, in part because you're not

  • going to bother others.

  • I saw quite a few people using their phones

  • in class in previous classes.

  • Try to not do that.

  • That's not good for you.

  • You will not be able to take away much from the class.

  • Multitasking is very hard for people to do.

  • Again, I'll show you some evidence on that.

  • As I said, the problem set will be posted shortly.

  • If you have any questions, please do let us know on Piazza

  • and help others answer them or answer them for others.

  • I have office hours, usually Tuesday afternoons.

  • Please sign up for them.

  • I'm very happy to meet you.

  • It's very hard for me to meet people or get to know you

  • in the large class otherwise.

  • So please come to office hours.

  • I'm happy to talk to you about anything

  • you're interested in, ideally related

  • to behavioral economics.

  • So let me give you an overview of this and the next lecture.

  • We're going to talk first about exponential discounting.

  • Why are we talking about exponential discount?

  • This is the workhorse model of classical economics.

  • This is how economists usually think about choices over time.

  • Second, we're going to identify some problems with this model,

  • and try to think about why is this model perhaps not

  • explaining things well, at least in some settings?

  • And how could we improve on that?

  • I'm going to propose an alternative model, which

  • is the quasi-hyperbolic discounting model.

  • And then we're going to talk about sophistication

  • and naivete, which is the idea that if you think

  • you have different preferences in the present form

  • in the future, then it becomes very important to understand.

  • Do you actually know what's going on?

  • Do you know that in the future you might be impatient,

  • or do you perhaps think that in the future,

  • I will be very patient, and then perhaps make

  • some mistakes accordingly?

  • I'll get to this in more detail.

  • So it's first important to notice

  • that any choice, essentially almost any choice you

  • make, almost always involves some choice over time.

  • Essentially, some trade-off between the present,

  • between some cost and benefit that you might occur

  • in the very short run, and some costs and benefits

  • that you might enjoy or incur in the future.

  • What examples do we have?

  • What choices over time do we face?

  • Yes.

  • STUDENT: Savings versus consumption.

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Uh-huh.

  • And how do you decide how much to save?

  • STUDENT: Depending on your preferences and interests,

  • right?

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Right.

  • So you have the choice, for example,

  • if you think about should I save some money, let's say,

  • for next semester or next year.

  • So your choice is either to consume the money now

  • in various ways-- eat food or whatever

  • you would like to do with it, spend it on various activities.

  • So if you save, if you make the decision to save,

  • you have to give up some money now,

  • and you get some benefits in the future.

  • The benefits in the future are determined by the interest

  • rate, as you say.

  • If you have a savings account or the like,

  • you can essentially get some benefits in the future.

  • And then you have some costs in the present, which

  • would be essentially not consuming now,

  • and some benefits in the future, which is getting

  • that money in the future.

  • And then you need to somehow decide is that worth doing.

  • There's some cost and benefit.

  • We need to aggregate somehow, whether to make that choice.

  • Any other choices you make over time?

  • Yes.

  • STUDENT: Whether to go to college or not

  • or start working right away and make some money

  • or delay that income.

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Right.

  • So I actually have this example here-- going to school.

  • It has some costs and benefits.

  • And what are the costs and benefits of doing that?

  • STUDENT: You sacrifice four years

  • or whatever right now versus supposedly

  • a higher income later on.

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Exactly.

  • So you have direct costs of education,

  • which is tuition in many cases.

  • Sometimes that's sponsored, but often there's tuition.

  • It's quite a bit of money.

  • It's also the opportunity cost, which is often forgone wages.

  • You could be working otherwise and make more money.

  • There's the joy of pain of going to school.

  • Some might think it's positive.

  • Some might think it's negative.

  • And then there's future wages, which in many cases,

  • at least for you guys, tend to be

  • higher from going to college.

  • If you do a PhD, that might not be the case.

  • I'm not sure if the TA's are here, but yes.

  • I'm sorry for that.

  • And then you have to decide are you going to school or not.

  • What do you need to do is you need to determine

  • the utility, the value of each of these costs and benefits.

  • And they occur in different points in time.

  • You need to make some estimates.

  • And then, of course, there's risk and other issues involved.

  • You might not have full information, and so on.

  • But assuming that all away, suppose

  • you knew all the costs and benefits of going to college.

  • Then you have to decide, is that worth doing?

  • So somehow you need to aggregate these costs and benefits

  • over time by putting appropriate weights

  • on different periods in time, and decide,

  • should I do this or not.

  • OK.

  • Yes, any other similar choices that people make?

  • Yes.

  • STUDENT: [INAUDIBLE]

  • FRANK SCHILBACH: Right.

  • For example, you could think about

  • should I do a problem set?

  • Should I come to class?

  • Should I study for an exam, and so on.

  • Often, there's costs and benefits involved.

  • Often, the costs are immediate.

  • You have to work on the problem set.